<samp id="e4iaa"><tbody id="e4iaa"></tbody></samp>
<ul id="e4iaa"></ul>
<blockquote id="e4iaa"><tfoot id="e4iaa"></tfoot></blockquote>
    • <samp id="e4iaa"><tbody id="e4iaa"></tbody></samp>
      <ul id="e4iaa"></ul>
      <samp id="e4iaa"><tbody id="e4iaa"></tbody></samp><ul id="e4iaa"></ul>
      <ul id="e4iaa"></ul>
      <th id="e4iaa"><menu id="e4iaa"></menu></th>

      代寫 CSCI1440/2440 Homework 3

      時間:2024-02-16  來源:  作者: 我要糾錯


      Homework 3: Myerson’s Lemma CSCI1440/2440

      2024-02-08

      Due Date: Tuesday, February 20, 2024. 11:59 PM.

      We encourage you to work in groups of size two. Each group need only submit one solution. Your submission must be typeset using LATEX. Please submit via Gradescope with you and your partner’s Banner ID’s and which course you are taking.

      For 1000-level credit, you need only solve the first three problems. For 2000-level credit, you should solve all four problems.

      1 The All-Pay Auction

      In an all-pay auction, the good is awarded to the highest bidder, but rather than only the winner paying, all bidders i must pay their bid: i.e., ui = vixi − pi.

      Using the envelope theorem, derive (necessary conditions on) the symmetric equilibrium of a symmetric all-pay auction in which the bidders’ values are drawn i.i.d. from some bounded distribution F.

      2 Allocation Rule Discontinuity

      Fix a bidder i and a profile v−i. Myerson’s lemma tells us that incen-

      tive compatibility and individual rationality imply two properties: 1. Allocation monotonicity: one’s allocation should not decrease as

       one’s value vi increases.

      2. Myerson’s payment formula:

      Z vi 0

      pi(vi,v−i) = vixi(vi,v−i)−

      xi(z,v−i)dz,

      ∀i ∈ [n],∀vi ∈ Ti,∀v−i ∈ T−i. (1)

      In a second-price auction, the allocation rule is piecewise constant on any continuous interval. That is, bidder i’s allocation function is a Heaviside step function,1 with discontinuity at vi = b∗, where b∗ is the highest bid among all bidders other than i (i.e., b∗ = maxj̸=i vj):

      1, if vi ≥ b∗ xi(vi,v−i) =

      0, otherwise. Observe that ties are broken in favor of bidder i.

      1 This is the canonical step function, whose range is [0, 1].

       

      Given this allocation rule, the payment formula tells us what i should pay, should they be fortunate enough to win:

      Z vi 0

      pi(vi,v−i) = vixi(vi,v−i)−

      ?Z b∗

      xi(z,v−i)dz

      =vi(1)−

      = vi(1)−(0+vi −b∗)

      = b∗.

      Alternatively, by integrating along the y-axis (i.e., R f (b) f −1 (y)dy),2

      f (a)

      bidder i’s payment can be expressed as follows: for ε ∈ (0, 1),

      2 As the allocation function, call it f , is not invertible, but is weakly

      increasing and right continuous, we define f(−1)(y) = inf{x | f(x) ≥ y}: e.g., f−1(1/2) = b∗.

      Z vi ?dx (z,v )? pi(vi,v−i) = z i −i dz

      Z ε Z 1−ε ?dxi(z,v−i)? = z(0)dz+ z

      Z vi ? 0dz+ ∗ 1dz

      0b

      homework 3: myerson’s lemma 2

      0 dz

      0 ε dz 1−ε Z1−ε ∗

      = bdy ε

      ∗ Z 1−ε =b dy ε

      = b∗,

      because the inverse of the allocation function is b∗, for all y ∈ (0, 1),

      and limε→0 R 1−ε dy = 1. Intuitively, we can conclude the following ε

      from this derivation: pi(vi, v−i) = b∗ · [jump in xi(·, v−i) at b∗]. Suppose that the allocation rule is piecewise constant on the con-

      tinuous interval [0, vi], and discontinuous at points {z1, z2, . . . , zl} in this interval. That is, there are l points at which the allocation jumps from x(zj, v−i) to x(zj+1, v−i) (see Figure 1). Assuming this “jumpy” allocation rule is weakly increasing in value, prove that Myerson’s payment rule can be expressed as follows:

      l

      pi(vi, v−i) = ∑ zj · ?jump in xi(·, v−i) at zj? . (2) j=1

      3 Sponsored Search Extension

      In this problem, we generalize our model of sponsored search to include an additional quality parameter βi > 0 that characterizes each bidder i. With this additional parameter, we can view αj as the probability a user views an ad, and βi as the conditional probability that a user then clicks, given that they are already viewing the ad. Note that αj, the view probability, depends only on the slot j, not

      Z 1

      dz+ z(0)dz

       

      xi(z3, v−i) xi(z2, v−i) xi(z1, v−i)

      Figure 1: Allocation Rule. Shaded area represents payment.

      z1z2 z3 Value, vi

      on the advertiser occupying that slot, while βi, the conditional click probablity, explicitly depends on the advertiser i.

      In this model, given bids v, bidder i’s utility is given by: ui(v) = βivix(v) − p(v)

      So if bidder i is allocated slot j, their utility is: ui(v) = βiviαj − p(v)

      Like click probabilities, you should assume qualities are public, not private, information.

      1.

      2.

      4

      optimization. The problem can be stated as follows:

      There is a knapsack, which can hold a maximum weight of W ≥ 0. There are n items; each item i has weight wi ≤ W and value vi ≥ 0. The goal is to find a subset of items of maximal total value with total weight no more than W.

      Written as an integer linear program,

      n

      max ∑ xivi

      x i=1

      Define total welfare for this model of sponsored search, and then describe an allocation rule that maximizes total welfare, given the bidders’ reports. Justify your answer.

      Argue that your allocation rule is monotonic, and use Myerson’s characterization lemma to produce a payment rule that yields a DSIC mechanism for this sponsored search setting.

      The Knapsack Auction

      The knapsack problem is a famous NP-hard3 problem in combinatorial

      3 There are no known polynomial-time solutions.

      homework 3: myerson’s lemma 3

      Allocation, xi(vi, v−i)

       

      subject to

      n

      ∑xiwi ≤W i=1

      xi∈{0,1}, ∀i∈[n]

      The key difference between optimization and mechanism design problems is that in mechanism design problems the constants (e.g., vi and wi) are not assumed to be known to the center / optimizer; on the contrary, they must be elicted, after which the optimization problem can then be solved as usual.

      With this understanding in mind, we can frame the knapsack problem as a mechanism design problem as follows. Each bidder

      has an item that they would like to put in the knapsack. Each item is characterized by two parameters—a public weight wi and a private value vi. An auction takes place, in which bidders report their values. The auctioneer then puts some of the items in the knapsack, and the bidders whose items are selected pay for this privilege. One real- world application of a knapsack auction is the selling of commercial snippets in a 5-minute ad break (e.g., during the Superbowl).4

      Since the problem is NP-hard, we are unlikely to find a polynomial- time welfare-maximizing solution. Instead, we will produce a polynomial- time, DSIC mechanism that is a 2-approximation of the optimal wel-

      fare. In particular, for any set possible set of values and weights, we

      aim to always achieve at least 50% of the optimal welfare.

      We propose the following greedy allocation scheme: Sort the bid- ders’ items in decreasing order by their ratios vi/wi, and then allocate items in that order until there is no room left in the knapsack.

      1. Show that the greedy allocation scheme is not a 2-approximation by producing a counterexample where it fails to achieve 50% of the optimal welfare.

      Alice proposes a small improvement to the greedy allocation scheme. Her improved allocation scheme compares the welfare achieved by the greedy allocation scheme to the welfare achieved

      by simply putting the single item of highest value into the knapsack.5 She then uses whichever of the two approaches achieves greater wel- fare. It can be shown that this scheme yields a 2-approximation of optimal welfare. We will use it to create a mechanism that satisfies individual rationality and incentive compatibility.

      2. Argue that Alice’s allocation scheme is monotone.

      3. Now use Myerson’s payment formula to produce payments such that the resulting mechanism is DSIC and IR.

      4 Here, the weight of a commercial is its time in seconds.

      homework 3: myerson’s lemma 4

      5 Note that weakly greater welfare could be achieved by greedily filling the knapsack with items in decreasing order of value until no more items

      fit. We do not consider this scheme, because it is unnecessary to achieve

      a 2-approximation; however, it is an obvious heuristic that anyone solving this problem in the real world
      請加QQ:99515681  郵箱:99515681@qq.com   WX:codehelp 

      標簽:

      掃一掃在手機打開當前頁
    • 上一篇:代寫ACP Assignment 1 Specificaons
    • 下一篇:代做ECON 323 Econometric Analysis 2
    • 無相關信息
      昆明生活資訊

      昆明圖文信息
      蝴蝶泉(4A)-大理旅游
      蝴蝶泉(4A)-大理旅游
      油炸竹蟲
      油炸竹蟲
      酸筍煮魚(雞)
      酸筍煮魚(雞)
      竹筒飯
      竹筒飯
      香茅草烤魚
      香茅草烤魚
      檸檬烤魚
      檸檬烤魚
      昆明西山國家級風景名勝區
      昆明西山國家級風景名勝區
      昆明旅游索道攻略
      昆明旅游索道攻略
    • 幣安app官網下載 幣安app官網下載

      關于我們 | 打賞支持 | 廣告服務 | 聯系我們 | 網站地圖 | 免責聲明 | 幫助中心 | 友情鏈接 |

      Copyright © 2023 kmw.cc Inc. All Rights Reserved. 昆明網 版權所有
      ICP備06013414號-3 公安備 42010502001045

      主站蜘蛛池模板: 久久亚洲精品无码VA大香大香| 亚洲精品无码专区久久久| 人妻无码一区二区三区AV| 无码伊人66久久大杳蕉网站谷歌| 久久AV高潮AV无码AV| 久久久久久无码国产精品中文字幕| 亚洲中文字幕不卡无码| 无码精品国产va在线观看dvd| 亚洲精品97久久中文字幕无码 | 亚洲的天堂av无码| 无码成人AAAAA毛片| 日韩人妻无码一区二区三区99| 亚洲AV无码资源在线观看| 亚洲av永久无码精品古装片| 免费无码又爽又高潮视频 | 日韩精品真人荷官无码| 国产高清无码二区 | 免费看又黄又无码的网站| 亚洲人成人无码网www国产| 亚洲中文无码亚洲人成影院| 国产成人无码区免费网站| 国产丝袜无码一区二区视频| 日韩av无码成人无码免费| 99久久无码一区人妻a黑| 久久久国产精品无码免费专区| 亚洲?V无码乱码国产精品| 国产高清不卡无码视频| 国产成人无码AV在线播放无广告 | 中文字幕无码人妻AAA片| 亚洲av无码一区二区三区人妖| 无码精品一区二区三区免费视频| 一区二区三区人妻无码| 国产又爽又黄无码无遮挡在线观看| 亚无码乱人伦一区二区| 亚洲日韩av无码中文| 亚洲中文字幕无码中文字| 亚洲一本到无码av中文字幕| 亚洲欧洲无码一区二区三区| 亚洲AV无码国产精品永久一区| 西西444www无码大胆| 无码熟熟妇丰满人妻啪啪软件|